A new
insider account reveals how the Obama administration’s botched bailout deal not
only reinforced neoliberal Clintonism, but also foreshadowed an ongoing failure
to fulfill campaign promises.
In November
2008, as a financial mudslide that had slowly been accelerating for months
accumulated increasingly persuasive comparisons to the collapse that triggered
the Great Depression in 1929, Time magazine ran a cover showing Barack Obama’s
smiling face inserted in place of Franklin Delano Roosevelt’s. The soon-to-be
forty-fourth president sits in the thirty-second’s open-topped car, wearing
Roosevelt’s lucky campaign hat, his grin gripping Roosevelt’s trademark long
cigarette-holder. The image suggested Obama, the president-elect who promised
hope and change, could follow in his Democratic predecessor’s footsteps.
Roosevelt met economic crisis with massive public works programs that gave the
dignity of employment to millions of Americans, and—more importantly in that
era of rising fascism—helped restore their faith in the U.S. government’s
ability to meet their needs.
Time’s
article about Obama-as-Roosevelt came a week after a New Yorker feature that
sported a similar illustration but took a more tempered view. There, journalist
George Packer quoted Cass Sunstein, Obama’s onetime academic colleague and
sometime political advisor, describing the newly elected president as
post-partisan and a “visionary minimalist”—a man little devoted to great
change. This attitude, Packer noted, made Obama “distinctly un-Rooseveltian.”
Before long, Packer’s more cautious view was vindicated. By 2009, when the
historian William E. Leuchtenburg put out a new edition of his book on the
post-1945 presidency, In the Shadow of FDR (1983), adding a chapter on Obama’s
first hundred days, Leuchtenburg could already note how frequently “Obama
expressed a degree of separation from the age of Roosevelt.” He even quoted the
new president as saying, “My interest is finding something that works. . . .
whether it’s coming from FDR or it’s coming from Ronald Reagan.”
For the
better part of a half century, the Democratic Party has been in this
multigenerational crisis over its past. Campaigning against Ronald Reagan in
1980, Jimmy Carter disowned the New Deal’s effort to put Wall Street in harness
to Washington, declaring “we believe that we ought to get the Government’s nose
out of the private enterprise of this country. We’ve deregulated . . . to make
sure that we have a free enterprise system that’s competitive.” Bill Clinton
fully assimilated Reaganism in 1996, saying “the era of big government is
over.” And now some progressive presidential candidates—together with a base of
millennial Democrats—are decrying Obama’s presidency as the last emanation of
the Carter-Reagan-Clinton synthesis, a retread of neoliberalism whose weak
program for recovery from the economic crisis of 2008 ensured nearly a decade
of employment doldrums that aided the rise of Donald Trump.
Reed Hundt,
once Clinton’s chair of the Federal Communications Commission and a member of
Obama’s transition team, has made the progressives’ argument effectively in his
new book A Crisis Wasted. Obama, Hundt believes, made decisions while still a
United States senator and then as president-elect that determined the course of
his presidency. In the post-election, pre-inauguration winter of 2008–2009, the
ordinarily maddeningly self-assured titans of finance—the same ones who,
earlier in the year, counseled government inaction in the interest of letting
the market discipline its own—were suddenly, and convincingly, prophesying doom
unless Washington did something dramatic to avert economic catastrophe. While
many voters hoped Obama’s policies might represent a dramatic change along the
lines of the New Deal, instead Obama acquiesced to emergency considerations and
ideological blandishments aimed at tempering expectations and a return to
“normalcy.”
Obama
swiftly switched from FDR redux to Clinton reborn because, Hundt points out, he
sought experienced advisors to staff his administration-in-waiting, and the
Democrats most accustomed to the White House were those who had served Bill
Clinton. Obama named Clinton’s chief of staff, John Podesta, to head his
transition team, and Podesta brought with him other Clinton appointees who
thought their job now was one of restoration. As Hundt writes, “People are
policy,” and the incoming Obama team wanted to bring back the policies of the
1990s and with them, the prosperity of that era. The Clinton personnel shared a
more Reaganesque than Rooseveltian view, believing their success in the late
twentieth century resulted from “a reduction in the size, capacity, and purpose
of the public sector.” The Clinton people, following Carter, believed the New
Deal had led ultimately to over-regulation and inhibition of capitalism’s great
energies, and that the long boom of the 1990s owed to their getting government
out of the way of business and banking, while still retaining state programs
necessary to promote opportunity for the majority of Americans.
Yet,
whatever one may think of the Clinton policies’ effects in the 1990s, the early
twenty-first century and its economic calamities called for a profoundly
different approach. The embryonic Obama administration’s adoption of
Clintonesque neoliberalism was not only an inadequate response to the economic
crisis. It also constituted, Hundt argues, a failure of the new president to
fulfill his campaign promises. Obama could have chosen to “align himself with
democracy, and then aim to help directly the great preponderance of Americans,”
Hundt says, but he did not. A critical mass of voters who had chosen hope and
change came to believe their president and their government did not represent
or even heed them—with consequences we now know.
Hundt’s book
makes an invaluable contribution to knowledge about this critical moment in
2008–2009. Because Hundt was there in Obama transition headquarters, he can
recall what he himself saw and heard. He has, since then, had access to key
figures who were there, too. Hundt’s notes attest to interviews with more than
a dozen officials who played important parts in crafting the Democratic policy
response to the crisis. At times their testimonies conflict with one another,
and Hundt lets them, which probably portrays with considerable accuracy the
uncertainty and disagreement that permeated the time.
The banking
relief bill, for example, represents how quickly policy was made during these
fraught weeks. The administration of George W. Bush had backed the bill in
September of 2008 in an effort to forestall a complete collapse of the banking
system; it allowed the president to spend large sums of money bailing out the
financial sector. The bill’s supporters, including Treasury Secretary Hank
Paulson and New York Federal Reserve Bank President Timothy Geithner, did
little outreach to Congress, believing the self-evident emergency should make
its own case. Geithner took the view, “I just wanted Congress to pass it as
fast as possible while screwing it up as little as possible.”
This style of
diplomacy initially failed to sway the House of Representatives, which rejected
the bill. But Senator Obama and other backers of the bill contacted the White
House to lend their support, and then lobbied members of Congress, changing
enough minds to get the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act through the House,
with a majority of Democrats and nearly half the Republicans lining up behind
it. When Obama and his Republican opponent, John McCain, both voted for the
bill from their seats in the Senate, Obama’s view that a matter of compelling
national concern could garner bipartisan support was vindicated. It was a hope
that carried over into the effort to craft a bill for bailing out the entire
economy.
Obama, among many
others, supported the bank bailouts because private lenders pump the lifeblood
of a capitalist economy, and as of the fall of 2008 they had nearly stopped
altogether. With the financial markets shut down, housing purchases and
business starts followed; unemployment began to rise. It would take time to clear
bank balance sheets and get credit circulating once more—time during which
Americans would find themselves without work, drawing down savings, unable to
pay their bills or ultimately to sustain shelter and food for themselves and
their families. They too needed assistance.
The method of
providing such aid was well known in economics and history: the government
ought to spend money to make up the shortfall, thus ensuring the employment of
Americans, continuing their borrowing and spending, and stimulating the
slumping economy back to action. As a rule of thumb, spending 2 percent of GDP
would bring down the unemployment rate by 1 percent. Economists in 2008 and
early 2009 realized that, given the jobless figures, an adequate spending
package would run at least $1 trillion and possibly more. Paul Krugman, the
economist who had just won the Nobel Prize, explained how to do the
calculations in his widely read New York Times column and blog.
Hundt’s book is
at its best in demonstrating how the stimulus legislation—the American Recovery
and Reinvestment Act—ended up nowhere near that number. Hundt has spoken with
Larry Summers, Christina Romer, Peter Orszag, and others who played a critical
role in determining the Obama pre-administration strategy for getting stimulus
money out of Congress. Hundt places his readers in the room. Romer, a professor
of economics from the University of California, Berkeley, who had written
considerably on the Great Depression, tried mightily to get the team to support
a bigger number; her own calculations suggested the stimulus should run around
$1.7 trillion. Summers, the former secretary of the Treasury under Clinton and
an estimable academic economist in his own right, did not dispute her
substantive conclusions; he simply thought the sum too daunting to get past Congress.
Orszag, also a former Clinton economic advisor and then director of the
Congressional Budget Office, understood that Obama wanted to keep health
insurance as a priority and was leery of ballooning deficits.
It is a rich and frustrating experience re-living these
contentious discussions, and in relating them, Hundt shines. He lets his
sources speak for themselves, differing sometimes not only on what they say
should have happened, but on what they say did happen. The book here is
gripping and appalling in approximately equal measure. Hundt clearly
sympathizes with Romer and the arithmetic. He also plainly understands that
gender was part of the reason she did not prevail. At one point in his
narrative, Romer tries to make an impression by swearing in front of the
president-elect. Obama uses it as an occasion to get a small laugh by calling
her out, and Hundt notes that this remark put Romer off in front of the
“male-dominated group.” (Hundt’s interview with Romer, like others, suggests
that profanity is not alien to her.) There was a clubbiness among the men who
had served in government before and who could claim the hard pragmatism of
experience.
Romer was right,
but somehow to be merely right was also to be basically unserious. Summers told
her not to mention the figure of $1.7 trillion; he talked her down even from
$1.2 trillion to something around $800 billion—which would leave unemployment
somewhere around 8 percent, the planners then believed. Even with a spending
bill that large, Hundt writes, the team’s “strategic goal was to end the
recession, but not to guarantee robust growth and a rising standard of living.”
The anti-Romer consensus carried the day, on the view that the Democrats should
demonstrate fiscal responsibility: “An excessive recovery package could spook
markets or the public and be counterproductive.” Congress did give them
essentially what they asked for, but barely, an anonymous source tells Hundt.
“Getting that 800 was very tenuous. It almost fell apart several times. Krugman
and everybody are always talking crap.”
In the end, the
stimulus would prove weaker than even Romer thought. Unemployment would remain
over 9 percent until late in 2011. The unimpressive recovery surely contributed
to the massive vote swing toward the Republicans in the 2010 midterm elections
and their takeover of the House of Representatives; the slow hard march back to
prosperity left many voters still bitter even in 2016. To the extent that the
decision to ask for a smaller stimulus resulted from, as David Axelrod tells
Hundt, “political judgments, not economic judgments,” it backfired. The
Democrats gained no evident support for their demonstration of restraint in
crafting a spending package, and their apparent ineptitude in fighting the
recession weakened them when afterward they sought vital environmental and
health care legislation.
The question,
then, is what the Obama team could, or should, have done differently. They
could have asked for more stimulus at the outset; even if it is true that they
could not have gotten more, at least they would have been on record as
believing more was necessary. Al Gore—among others—warned it would be much
harder to get a second stimulus bill after a failed first one than it would be
to get a big bill at the start. Romer wanted at least to manage expectations
and explain how modest an $800 billion stimulus might prove. “Why can’t we actually
say the truth?” she asks, at one point. Instead, the Obama team negotiated
against themselves, choosing a lower number, and then saying they believed it
to be sufficient.
Hundt also argues
that by the time Obama’s team was considering a stimulus bill, they were already
in a bad bargaining position. Before the election, Obama had endorsed the bank
relief bill without even discussing the need for borrowers’ relief. At the
time, Speaker of the House Nancy Pelosi, Hundt says, reacted to the bank relief
bill by saying, “You’ve got to be kidding,” and urging that there be “money for
Main Street as well as Wall Street.” But the Bush administration, with Obama’s
support, deferred the stimulus discussion and, Hundt believes, thus “snared”
Obama. The bipartisanship that had so energized Obama vanished once Wall Street
got its life preserver.
In the end the
comparison to Roosevelt still haunts the Obama team. The economist Austan
Goolsbee tells Hundt that the Obama people consciously chose not to emulate
Roosevelt who, in their view, deliberately “let things get so bad” by not
cooperating with outgoing president Herbert Hoover in the months before his
inauguration that he arrived in the White House with a prostrate Congress
willing to do any of his bidding. Roosevelt, in their view, sacrificed his
countrymen to gain political advantage.
Goolsbee is here
echoing Geithner and Obama himself, who have made similar remarks in their
defense over the years. Their history of Roosevelt’s behavior in the bad early
months of 1933 is so similar, they must have got it from a common source. In
any event, Roosevelt did no such thing: Hoover did not offer cooperation to his
waiting successor; rather, he demanded capitulation from him. Writing to
President-elect Roosevelt, Hoover explained that his successor could combat the
Depression only by forswearing inflation, budget deficits, and the massive
public works programs he had promised in the campaign, thus proving himself a
fiscally responsible Democrat. Only by making these pledges, Hoover said, could
Roosevelt restore confidence and allow the easily upset engines of finance and
business to resume their proper operations. Privately, to a fellow Republican,
Hoover admitted he was not seeking any joint venture; rather, he was asking
Roosevelt to trade his own agenda for Hoover’s: “I realize that if these declarations
be made by the president-elect, he will have ratified the whole major program
of the Republican Administration; that it means the abandonment of 90 percent
of the so-called new deal.”
Roosevelt
declined the Republican’s request for surrender. In thus evading the trap
Hoover had laid out, Roosevelt ensured he could fulfill his campaign promises.
Democracy around the world was in a bad position, Roosevelt believed, and he
aimed to restore it. That was why he had told voters he would get Congress to
adopt unemployment and old-age insurance, minimum wages and maximum hours laws,
subsidies for farmers, and also to provide jobs on public works—not merely so
that Americans would have incomes, but so they would feel their government
worked for them. In building a dam or an airport or a road, in running
electrical lines across a landscape to people who never had access to modern
energy before, literally bringing power to the people, Washington would “help
restore the close relationship with its people which is necessary to our
democratic form of government.”
Rather than seeking
the chimera of bipartisan cooperation, Obama could have done more to preserve
his campaign pledges of progressive hope and change. In so doing, he could have
done something to restore Americans’ confidence in our institutions and our
democratic form of government. Alas, as Hundt notes, it was a crisis wasted.
Hundt takes up
the comparison between Obama and Roosevelt in an extended riff at the end of
his book. Unfortunately, he makes an error in dealing with the 1930s that he
avoided in dealing with the 2000s and relies on a single—and unusually
undependable—source; Hundt draws almost entirely on the memoirs of the
disaffected (and Barry Goldwater–supporting) former Roosevelt aide, Raymond
Moley, for his account of the New Deal. It is as if Hundt had relied
exclusively on Geithner’s memoir to understand Obama’s administration. But
nobody will pick up Hundt’s book for his analysis of the Roosevelt era. People
should read it when considering which parts of the Democratic Party’s past
should be saved, and which are best left behind.
Obama's Original
Sin. By Erich Rauchway. Boston Review , April
23, 2019
Every Democrat
who aspires to win the presidency in 2020 (or ever) should already be asking
the question: How do we avoid what happened to Barack Obama and his ideas in
the fall of 2008?
Obama was, of
course, the progressive candidate. He built a lane to the left of Hillary
Clinton in the course of 2007 and then expanded it into a broad highway along
which he could coast to victory in November 2008. The hope and change he
promised was in no way about continuity with the past. Yet what President Obama
delivered, over two administrations, was profoundly disappointing—and directly
contributed to the rise of dangerous and despotic Donald.
The trite riposte
is that Obama was overtaken by events. In mid-September 2008, Lehman Brothers
went bankrupt. Lehman was a significant trader of and investor in
mortgage-backed securities, with total liabilities of around $600 billion. The
knock-on effect of this failure was much larger than expected by officials,
quickly threatening to bring down a very large insurance company (AIG), other
investment banks (Goldman Sachs, Morgan Stanley, and Merrill Lynch), and even
the largest bank in the country (Citigroup), which had total debts close to
$2.5 trillion.
It was not
immediately obvious that the crisis would derail the Obama agenda. Initially,
in fact, Obama seemed calmer and more likely to respond effectively to the
disaster than his Republican opponent, John McCain. As Reed Hundt points out in
A Crisis Wasted: Barack Obama’s Defining Decisions, a meticulous blow-by-blow
reconstruction of Obama’s transition to power, for a brief moment everything
seemed possible—including perhaps reforms as profound as the New Deal. Here was
a newly elected leader who could produce, no matter how difficult the moment, a
just and equitable set of solutions.
Instead, what the
country got was Republicans in charge, literally. The three main
decision-makers of the moment, Ben Bernanke, Tim Geithner, and Hank Paulson,
have a new, jointly written book, Firefighting: The Financial Crisis and Its
Lessons. Their slim volume is a further attempt to explain and defend what they
did. Combine this volume with their three individual memoirs, and it starts to
feel like they doth protest a bit too much in unison.
Bernanke is a
Republican who was nominated to the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
by George W. Bush—before becoming the chair of Bush’s Council of Economic
Advisers and then chairman of the Fed. Paulson led Goldman Sachs until being
brought in by Bush as Treasury Secretary. Geithner had a more bipartisan
career—rising to prominence in the Clinton Treasury, becoming a senior official
at the International Monetary Fund, moving to lead the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York under the auspices of influential Wall Street Republicans and
Democrats, and then hired by Obama to be his first Treasury Secretary. Geithner
is a political independent (and former Republican); Bernanke and Paulson are
long-standing Republicans.
“Personnel is
policy” is a Washington cliché that also happens to be true. Let me venture a
corollary: If you hire Republicans, you will get Republican policy.
Of course, there
are several kinds of Republicans in the modern era, measured in terms of what
they really believe. And it is becoming harder to know what some of them
believe. Irrespective of their previously expressed views or votes, most
congressional Republicans will turn their backs on anything reasonable if
proposed by a Democratic president—and support even the most outrageous
expedient if supported by Donald Trump.
However,
Bernanke, Geithner, and Paulson are genuine Status Quo Republicans, and this is
quite evident in their book. In their view, the world was basically fine before
2007. A modest fire broke out in that year and, despite their best efforts,
became an inferno. When fighting a fire, surely, there is no time to argue
about redecorating the living room. The fire was extinguished, the world was
saved, and they continue to be surprised that we are not all more grateful.
Everything in
this interpretation of events—and in their view of history—hinges on the
metaphor of fire, chaotic and uncontrolled. No doubt the authors feel they are
reaching out to people by popularizing economics; there are no tables or
figures in their book, and very few numbers. But the metaphor is a smoke
screen. This was not any kind of fire. Extreme financial deregulation allowed
blue-chip financial-sector executives to make large bets backed by very thin
amounts of equity. The bets went bad, and potential cumulative losses at their
banks threatened dire consequences for the economy.
Status Quo
Republicans have a simple preference in this situation: use all available
central-bank and government resources to cover those losses fully and with no
repercussions for those responsible. The accurate name for this approach is
Lemon Socialism, meaning in this case: financial sector executives get the
upside when things go well; you (the taxpayer, the unemployed, and the
dispossessed) own the lemons when the economy turns down.
Bernanke-Geithner-Paulson
did not invent Lemon Socialism. They did perhaps take it to a new level. The
U.S., contrary to what is (sometimes) claimed by Expedient Republicans, has a
strong national balance sheet and a highly credible central bank—so massive
amounts of government support could be deployed. As a result, highly
compensated bank executives generally did very well from the boom-bust cycle.
Investors who had cash in hand were even better placed to snap up distressed assets
and experience steep capital appreciation. They (not you) got the upside—and
then the Trump tax cuts let them keep more (or perhaps almost all) of those
gains.
This is the real
reason that Donald Trump’s Treasury Department is currently working hard to
undermine financial regulation. It is not at all because they have forgotten
what happened and why. The explanation is much simpler: Top current officials
made good money in the crisis. If you know how to play the game, the roller
coaster of modern finance works just fine. As Trump himself said in 2006, when
asked about the prospect of a major fall in house prices, “I sort of hope that
happens because then people like me would go in and buy.”
This brings us
back to Reed Hundt, who is asking the
important questions. Was there an alternative way forward in the fall of 2008?
Why was that not followed? After all, there were plenty of actual Democrats in
the White House, including Christy Romer at the Council of Economic Advisers,
Larry Summers at the National Economic Council, and Peter Orszag at the Office
of Management and Budget.
Reed Hundt was
chairman of the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) under President
Clinton, and he had a ringside seat for the meteoric political rise of Barack
Obama. As a member of the Obama transition team in 2008, Hundt had access to
everyone and apparently remains on good terms with the leading players. He
argues persuasively that the major Obama-era decisions were all taken in late
2008 and the very beginning of 2009.
Hundt’s book is
based on interviews and it sometimes reads like a loose synthesis of oral
histories or even depositions. But this is actually refreshing. The articulate
protagonists approved the quotes that he uses.
Hundt feels that
the underlying political beliefs of Clinton-era officials were part of the
problem. He uses the term “neoliberal” rather frequently and not always with
great precision, but his general instinct is right. Top officials from the Clinton
era retained a greater preference for less regulation and a generally smaller
role for government than, for example, Hundt would prefer. Their style of
economic governance from the 1990s was to score singles and steal bases, not
swing for the fences.
Hundt is right
that more could have been done, but it is hard to design a dramatically new
policy once you are in office—the press of events tends to dominate, even when
there is not a confusing, fast-evolving international crisis. Obama did not
bring with him a large, experienced team, and during the campaign he developed
only broad-brush ideas. The experts on the details were almost all people who
had worked with the Clintons. They were Small Ball Democrats—smart people with
admirable ideas, but hardly in a position to stand up to Status Quo
Republicans. New Deal–style Democrats were conspicuous by their absence.
The financial
sector was saved, largely intact, by unprecedented government support. If
homeowners had received the same level of support in 2008-2009—for example, in
the form of cheap refinanced mortgages—what would have happened? The American
economy would have recovered, house prices would have risen, and everyone
involved would have looked like a genius. Modern central banks control the
price level and this has a primary, direct effect on asset prices—including
housing. In most of the country, house prices bounced back but millions of
homeowners could not finance their way through the trough. Powerful people in
the financial sector could obtain cheap loans, even in the darkest days,
because their access to credit was the top priority for both the Bush and Obama
administrations.
The result, in
rough chronological order, was: mass unemployment, greater inequality,
collapsed opportunity, confused anger, and President Trump. The efforts put
into financial reform—making sure this could not happen again—by Messrs. Bernanke,
Geithner, and Paulson were weak. They lament that next time the central bank
will not have the tools to deal with an incipient crisis. If that proves true,
it is because their generation undermined the legitimacy of the Federal Reserve
through inattention to regulation, consumer protection, and blatant bad
behavior before the crisis, and through subsequently allowing the Too Big To
Fail banks to become even larger and more dangerous—the total indebtedness of
JPMorgan Chase today is in the range of $2.5 trillion.
What are the
implications for people who would like to call themselves progressives? Hundt
has a broader vision of what government could do, but the details remain
slightly elusive. He argues that the FCC in the 1990s helped create the basis
for broader investments in the digital economy, and this benefited many people.
He also suggests there are analogies that could be implemented for energy,
clean water, and much more. Probably he should develop those ideas more fully
in another book—and preferably soon.
You might or
might not like the work of the Hamilton Project, organized in 2006 under the
auspices of the Brookings Institution, but there is no question that they
helped prepare the Small Ball Democrats for another round in power. Not only
were their ideas tested in numerous proposals, panel discussions, and debates,
but their smart young people were given every possible policymaking
opportunity.
When Obama did
make progress, for example in terms of extending health-care coverage, it was
in part because of these diligent efforts. When Obama struggled, from a
progressive point of view, it was primarily due to problems in the financial
sector—a blind spot in terms of Hamilton Project preparation. Anyone who thinks
that President Obama did all he could to advance a progressive agenda, under
difficult constraints, should ponder this: Why were progressive Democrats shut
out of almost all influential positions throughout the Obama years?
It is unlikely
that the next Democratic president will want to be seen as another
reincarnation of the Clinton administration. But are the potential home-run
policy ideas being debated and honed in sufficient detail? Who will be
hired—and with what experience—to be in charge of implementation? What are the
plans for regulating the financial sector, which is more powerful than ever?
And who exactly will be in charge when anything starts to go wrong in the
macroeconomy? On these questions may turn both the election and the future of
American democracy
The Crisis Last
Time. By Simon Johnson . The American Prospect. March 29, 2019
Review of : A Crisis Wasted: Barack Obama's Defining
Decisions. By Reed Hundt. Rosetta Books
Firefighting: The
Financial Crisis and Its Lessons. By Ben
S. Bernanke, Timothy F. Geithner, & Henry M. Paulson Jr. Penguin Books
In their new
book, Ben Bernanke, Timothy Geithner, and Henry Paulson describe fighting the
fire of the 2008 financial crisis. But while they did rebuild the burnt towers
of Wall Street, they left Main Street to dig out from the rubble.
The Great Crash
of 2007–2009 stripped American middleclass families of wealth. It gave rise to
nativist politics on the right and socialism on the left, killing credence in
neoliberal market capitalism in both the United States and Europe. It buried
the Washington consensus that had energized bipartisan support for U.S.
leadership around the world. Indeed, China has replaced the United States as
the leading country whose investment drives the global economy.
In his 2018
letter to shareholders, Jamie Dimon, CEO of JPMorgan Chase, described the state
of the union as follows: “Middle class incomes have been stagnant for years.
Income inequality has gotten worse. Forty percent of American workers earn less
than $15 an hour, and about 5% of full-time American workers earn the minimum
wage or less, which is certainly not a living wage. In addition, 40% of
Americans don’t have $400 to deal with unexpected expenses, such as medical
bills or car repairs.”
According to
Dimon, cumulative economic growth over the last decade has been half of what it
would have been in a normal recovery. As a result the economy is $4 trillion
smaller than it should be. In his words, that growth “certainly would have
driven wages higher and given us the wherewithal to broadly build a better
country.”
It is widely
recognized that the economic disappointments of the last decade made it
extremely difficult for the Democratic presidential nominee in 2016 to run on
her predecessor’s record, even though unemployment was at last reaching satisfactorily
low levels and wages had begun to increase. Conversely, Donald Trump’s
successful campaign is often seen as reflecting voter dissatisfaction with the
government’s response to the financial crisis of 2008.
Given the ample
volume of hindsight, it takes conviction verging on stubbornness to insist that
the United States government under the Bush administration did all it could to
prevent the crisis and that both the Bush and Obama administrations did all
they reasonably could have done in response. Yet in their three separate memoirs,
numerous public statements, and now in their jointly written book,
Firefighting: The Financial Crisis and Its Lessons, the trio of President
Bush’s Treasury Secretary Hank Paulson, President Obama’s Treasury Secretary
Tim Geithner, and both presidents’ Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke have made these
claims.
Historians will
debate the events of 2007–2009 for decades, and the leading actors, namely the
trio of Bernanke, Geithner, and Paulson, should be complimented for their many
good steps as well as their willingness to account for their decisions. But
they were wrong in 2008, and they are especially wrong now to promote the wrong
lessons from their experience. In Firefighting, for instance, they look to the
next crisis and correctly assert that the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC) should be able to “fully stand behind” the obligations “of large
complicated banks on the brink of failure . . . while winding them down in an
orderly fashion.” But in an FDIC resolution shareholders and creditors take
some loss. The firefighters rejected that approach in 2008, and they continue
now to argue that in a crisis it is wrong “to ensure that risk takers pay a
price for their risk taking” such as by “imposing haircuts on creditors.” By
arguing that risk takers should be held harmless in the next crisis, they are
restating the position that tied President Obama to one of the most unpopular
government actions in history—namely, the bail-out. No future president should,
or would want, to take this advice.
Notwithstanding
many actions by the trio in emergency conditions, their reaction to the
recession was not what the country deserved. Indeed, it had at least three
serious flaws that we should be revisiting and learning from for next time.
First, they
bailed out Bear Stearns in March 2008, let Lehman Brothers go bankrupt on
September 15, 2008, and bailed out AIG on September 16, 2008. In the first of
these moves, they had another firm buy the failing firm. In the middle
decision, they magnified the losses for everyone by implementing no plan in
advance. And in the last of these moves, the government took control and fired
management.
This
unpredictable signaling intensified the dreadful reaction to the Lehman
bankruptcy. The government’s sinuous path of decision-making inspired a lack of
confidence. That in turn contributed to the over-reaction of the real economy
to the financial crisis, leading to excessive reductions in investment and
employment.
Second, at all
times, the trio’s top priority should have been helping the real economy
recover from the economic calamities of the Great Crash. At the time, it was no
secret that domestic construction jobs were evaporating and consumer consumption
was falling. Housing prices had also plummeted: ultimately, homeowners’ equity
fell from nearly $14 trillion to about $6 trillion. But instead of taking
actions to help Americans, the trio (and the presidents they advised) chose
strengthening the financial sector as their primary objective. The misguided
belief was that by instilling confidence in the balance sheets of big financial
firms, they could cause benefits to flow through to Main Street.
This error in
strategic goals led to a series of bad policies. First, instead of passing what
the trio refer to as a “small” fiscal stimulus composed of tax cuts in February
2008, the Republican White House could have joined with the Democratic Congress
to jumpstart more spending. Second, instead of protecting firms from having to
take write downs on the debt and mortgage securities they held on their balance
sheets, the trio could have used the authority of the Housing and Economic Recovery
Act (HERA) to re-finance or restructure troubled mortgage loans or constrain
foreclosures in a meaningful way. Third, instead of the modest recovery program
enacted in February 2009, the trio could have championed a significantly larger
recovery program. Geithner, in a memorandum he co-wrote with Larry Summers
(likely with Bernanke’s input too) for President-elect Obama on December 15,
2008, recommended that the second economic stimulus to create Main Street jobs
not be greater than approximately $800 billion because an “excessive recovery
package could spook markets or the public and be counterproductive.” And
fourth, instead of returning the $200 billion in unspent bailout money to
Congress after the big banks had passed the stress tests in 2009, the trio
could have spent the unused bailout money to protect homeowners and jumpstart
job creation.
The third serious
flaw in the recovery effort was that the Troubled Asset Relief Program was not
a good law. Its principal defect was that Paulson could act with no
supervision: he could buy whatever he wanted (including the most spurious
assets traded). Moreover, no bank benefitting from the one-sided sale would
suffer any limitation on bonuses much less replacement of management, and the
actual amount of government funding would prove more than twice what the
banking system actually needed for recapitalization.
In Firefighting,
the trio acknowledge that the post-Lehman crisis compelled TARP’s
passage—indeed, the trio have argued for a decade that Congress would not pass
a useful bill without a crisis. But it is more accurate to conclude that the
trio’s approach invited an avoidable crisis in order to pass a bad law. Indeed,
the smoke of the Lehman explosion was the only reason a bill that awful could
be pushed through Congress.
The timing, too,
in retrospect is suspect. In September of 2008, for example, the trio had told
Congress that the emergency required weekend action. This proved untrue.
Moreover, by the time TARP was enacted in October 2008, some of the biggest
Wall Street firms in which Paulson insisted on investing did not even need or
want the money. The TARP legislation is not a model of what was then or is now
desirable. Instead, in 2010, Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer
Protection Act wisely used the FDIC to guarantee troubled firms’ obligations
while meting out haircuts to equity and debt holders as the method for
recovery.
None of this is
to argue that drastic times do not call for drastic measures. But when a fire
seems poised to break out again in the financial sector, government leaders
should throw water on the sparks instead of waiting for a full-fledged
conflagration. And if the fire rages anyhow, government should not rebuild the
burnt towers of Wall Street while leaving Main Street to dig out from the
rubble. The real economy is more important than the financial sector. Indeed,
in the next crisis or before, the financial sector should help fund, through
taxes or mandated investment, the recovery of the real economy. Perhaps then
the financial sector might not grow as dangerously large as it has.
Exactly what
needs to be done when the next crisis hits cannot be precisely predicted, but
whoever fights that fire must remember that transparent, equitable, and
justice-delivering government is not expendable. When the going gets tough,
tough-minded government leaders have to trust that the United States can
recover from the worst of financial shocks but know that it cannot long survive
an ethic of saving the well-off at the cost of the rest of the country. What
Theodore Roosevelt called the “malefactors of great wealth” should at least
lose some of that wealth as their just desserts are served.
Playing with Fire.
By Reed Hundt. Boston Review . May 10,
2019.
No comments:
Post a Comment